It is heartwarming to see a scholarly work of Economics
become so popular. In case you have missed it, the book in question is Capital
in the 21st Century, by Frenchman Thomas Piketty, and it is
outselling pretty well everything except Twilight and hunger Games just now.
I understand the book is long and detailed, and I don’t
intend to read it myself. So I am grateful to the Economist and some other
publications for reviewing it so thoroughly. To its credit, the Economist has
been quite balanced in its critique, even though the attitude of the book lies
far to its left. The FT has also given serious attention, but seems more
inclined to pick at the logic and proofs than try to see the bigger picture.
Even that approach shows that the FT is scared.
The basic premise of the book, supported by reams of
historical analysis, is that capital tends to grow faster than the wider
economy, so those with capital tend to get richer quicker than those who don’t
and inequality tends to widen. The period from about 1930-1980 was a historical
exception, one that spawned the dominant economics agenda of today. Which,
according to Piketty, is wrong-headed and disastrous.
Like most ground-breaking theories, this one is simple and
elegant. It feels true, based on recent observations. And Piketty seems to show
that it is true historically as well. He advocates a global wealth tax, among
other unlikely measures, as the most effective antidote.
Some people have claimed that capital does not usually grow
so quickly as Piketty claims. For me, the most elegant evidence is the
assumptions capitalists make about future capital growth. Most notably, almost
all our pension investments actually need to grow at something like 6% real to
avoid a black hole appearing in state and corporate coffers, not to mention
banks.
So 6% is dutifully assumed in pension models, pushing the
can down the road. Piketty only claims 4%, which is probably attainable. It
could be argued that the 6% assumption is the root cause of many failings, creating
unrealistic expectations of company boards, passed on via ever-more desperate
lobbying, aggressive short-term goals and heartless labour policies, and
stressed out executives comforted only by their ridiculous bonuses.
6% is not attainable long-term, but maybe 4% real is, and
that is roughly what Piketty calculates. And capital can hardly argue against
that when their own models require an even higher return.
Once Piketty establishes his simple equation and
demonstrates the devastating consequences, the really interesting is what
global society can do about it. Piketty advocates socialist style
redistribution remedies. Chief among them is a global wealth tax, supported by
progressive income and property taxes and a heavy inheritance tax. I am sure Tobin
will be in there too if I read into the detail.
As a European, I support all this, but, as someone living in
the US, I see the scale of the gap to close before any of it gains currency
here. The greedy have done such a thorough job of selling their liberty and
small government message that it becomes political suicide (for now at least)
to argue for progressive measures.
I am particularly pleased to see the Piketty focus on
inheritance tax. This is such an emotional issue. We all want the best for our
children, and to feel the state will steal our legacy is tough to accept. But
don’t we have enough opportunity within our lifetimes to set our children up?
If it is our true priority, wouldn’t we invest more in them while we were still
alive? And isn’t this the single most obvious example of unequal opportunity?
I was staggered to learn that in the US the minimum
inheritance tax threshold is five million dollars. That is enough to set up a
small family for life without contributing even a cent of tax, or without
taking account of what parents can do to evade the tax or pass on assets while
alive. It is perhaps the loudest signal of all of a structural unequal society.
But it is such a hard sell to change, striking at the heart of our desires as
parents.
So we will wait a long time for progressive redistribution.
Still, the tide has to start to turn before it can roll back, so well done
Piketty (and the OECD, and even the Economist) for igniting the debate. But I
think I have spotted an alternative opportunity, one that might just be more
palatable to the vested interests.
Piketty highlights the period from 1930-1980 as an exception
to his rule, a time when inequality declined. It is telling to understand why.
In response to crisis and war, governments between 1930-1980 invested at an
unusually high level.
It is important to distinguish government spending with
investment. The difference is between running costs and capital improvements.
You don’t necessarily have to spend more overall to invest more. The small
government brigade will of course argue differently.
Now the question is – what stops a massive global injection
of investment right now? The potential benefits are huge.
In the developed world, we could establish pre-school for
all. We could upgrade roads and public transport and create green and
sustainable cities. We could ensure quality housing for all. We could set up
care systems for our old.
In the developing world we could establish infrastructure,
including internet, for all. We could bring universal education to the current
level of developed countries. We could eradicate many diseases and early
deaths. With some help, we could establish corruption-free institutions.
All of this is feasible with current technology. All it
takes is money. A by-product would be full employment, since many of the
projects require many willing workers. Further, if addressed globally, the
money can simply be printed. It is not possible for the world to rack up debt
(at least not monetary debt), since debt is a zero-sum game.
What would be necessary is to prevent government from
dominating the implementation. Government should nudge and steer, but not
necessarily spend or employ. Since starting these projects up would add to
government spending in the short-term, we should be open to privatisations and
partnership financing to offset this. That argues for things like free schools
and more market-based health.
So why not? Blind orthodoxy is one reason – with the IMF
doing a reasonable job but sometimes in thrall to financiers. A lack of global
consensus is another – if for example Germany chose not to participate they
would build up surpluses and plunge the rest into more debt.
All this could be overcome were it not for the vested
interests. For this scheme creates billions of winners, but a few losers, that
is those with capital today. There are a couple of reasons. One is inflation,
which would grow with investment, deflating the value of savings, in other
words reducing the net worth of the wealthy. Another reason is that full
employment would rebalance power between capital and labour. Living wages would
emerge from the market, reducing profits.
I can’t see any other downsides. And these don’t really feel
like downsides, merely necessary rebalancing. We can even use the famous
trickle down answer in reverse. Capital today argues that their orthodoxy
maximizes growth, which trickles down to all. Recent evidence scarcely supports
the claim but they still make it. We could argue the converse. Investment
rebalances wealth, but even the wealthy benefit from the social gains.
The tragedy here is less inequality and more squandered
global development. We could make the world so much better for every single
citizen, right now. Progress was wonderful from 1930-80; there has been
progress since but at a slower pace. What a waste that is, and all to protect
the citadel of privilege. If Piketty can help turn that tide, we all owe him a
huge debt.
No comments:
Post a Comment