I admire
the way The Economist has recently taken on the challenge of supporting
globalisation’s losers. Having been a shameless champion of free markets, small
government, privatisation and other modern orthodoxies, they have paused to
observe the unwelcome side effects, and to try to find some solutions.
The need
for action is clear. Inequality is a curse of our times, and neo-liberalism
makes it worse by design, in the name of incentive, dynamism and growth. One of
the weak spots for Trump that Democrats are not exploiting (being constantly
side-tracked into identity issues) is the impact of key policies to exacerbate
inequality. Gut healthcare and the poor suffer, and the tax plan will
redistribute further to the rich. The main part of this redistribution is due
to the love affair the administration has with corporate America. We have
already seen the biggest effect, because stock markets have responded to the
promises of lighter regulation and lower taxes already. This is touted as a
good thing, and in some respects it is, but who is benefiting? Of course it is
those who own stocks. That is most of us to an extent, through our pension
plans, but it is mainly the wealthy. It was the struggling white working class
that elected Trump, and to defeat him the opposition message has to resonate
with the same people. That means less talk about civil rights and more about
inequality.
The
Economist takes this argument a step back, and sees inequality and hopelessness
as reasons Trump and other populists get elected in the first place. Hence the
need for a story to correct the most glaring negative consequences to halt the
tide of populism before it becomes entrenched.
Previous
articles have focused on how to help people who have lost out, and recommended
the old chestnuts of education and transitional support, as well as help with
mobility. The most recent essay instead looked at places. People who lose out
are concentrated in rural areas and places where heavy industry leaves. Giving people
more weapons to move out from these places is admirable, but tends to make
things even worse for those still left behind.
This was an
issue even before globalisation turbo charged it. We have hears of Scottish
districts populated only be the old and incapable, and of Japanese prefectures
becoming older and older. The South of Italy has been a basket place for
generations. Now we also have places like Detroit and Baltimore, and smaller
districts like parts of north-east Pennsylvania or West Virginia, places where
a large employment cluster previous attracted families, and then abandoned them
as business dried up.
The
symptoms are brutal. Departing people leads to poorer schools, depressed house
prices and crime. For those that don’t escape early, there is no escape. The
local government has too much infrastructure to maintain and too many pensions
to pay, with not enough taxpayers to pay them.
And trends
will make this worse, as jobs overall will become scarcer while the old live
longer. The slow death of retail will remove more jobs and also civic pride and
places to meet. It is no wonder such districts become crime ridden, and readily
turn to opioids and populist politics.
Having
described the problem, The Economist was disappointing in advocating solutions.
Mostly, the discussion centred on enterprise zones or similar initiatives,
designed to create new skill and employment hubs. These have a mixed record. I
have seen them work myself, while visiting the Algarve and other poorer parts
of Europe, where EU structural funds have helped to drag such places upwards.
The article
went into lots of detail about which sort of assistance works and which
doesn’t, though the evidence is patchy. Just paying subsidies does little,
seemingly, and any positive effects vanish once payments stop. Trying to set up
new businesses can also fail, unless somehow a cluster emerges, like in South
Carolina after BMW elected to build a factory there.
It is no
wonder that cities are bidding so aggressively for Amazon’s HQ2. But in a way,
that is the problem, because it is another example of corporate power. The
bigger winners will be Amazon and its wealthy shareholders, more than the
citizens of HQ2.
The
Economist’s only slightly radical idea was for the public sector to try create
sorts of clusters, for example with research facilities around colleges. This
is how things always used to happen. I have submitted paperwork to national
vehicle licensing offices in Swansea, Kiruna and Mo I Rana, the last two near
the Arctic Circle and all chosen to give stable public sector employment to
struggling places.
The must
also be mileage in supporting places in efforts at smart rightsizing, as they
attempt to get out of the negative cycle of decline with fundamental fixes.
Detroit could turn into a positive example here. Key to their latest attempted
regeneration is housing, destroying the stock in distressed areas and trying to
nudge people into a reshaped city designed for its modern needs. Funding such
investment locally is always tough, and the public sector, or some
public-private funds, could focus on this.
Linked to
this could come some more creative marketing and specialisation of districts.
Why does everyone have to have classical employers? Could some cities focus on
trying to be ideal places to live for older people, for example? That would
imply different priorities in transport, housing, health care and leisure –
some rebirth of civic centres perhaps.
However,
the real solution might require the Economist and others challenging their real
sacred cows. Should the public sector always be reduced, is there a right size
for that, and have many developed nations now shrunk it too much? Think of
things the public sector usually provides, especially and education and health
care. Even if provision is via private contractors, these can be regulated or
steered to equalise regional disparity. They offer jobs where wages can be
closer to nationally set. And in some areas, like defence or health research,
the national government can choose locations to favour regions with other
disadvantages.
A universal basic income would help here, and perhaps that will arrive sooner rather than later, as classical jobs become ever more scarce. My alternative to universal income would be paying people for care, an idea that would help reduce inequality even more.
A universal basic income would help here, and perhaps that will arrive sooner rather than later, as classical jobs become ever more scarce. My alternative to universal income would be paying people for care, an idea that would help reduce inequality even more.
So The
Economist and others blame the phenomenon on globalisation, but actually the
drive to small central government could be the true culprit. Starving public
sector wages and services harm weaker areas disproportionally. You can hardly
find a bus in the UK nowadays except on commuter routes.
I am not
advocating collectivism or mass nationalisation here, merely a rebalance away
from its extreme opposite. Regional hardship is just one of the consequences of
the Great Wrong Turning around 1980; indeed almost all the consequences have
been negative. We should remember that the Great Wrong Turning was not an
inevitable consequence of globalisation, but an active choice by doctrinaire
governments. The public have been duped. And that is why we now have the ugly
rise of populism. Once The Economist starts to recognise that, then at last the
tide might start to turn.
No comments:
Post a Comment